Given all the discussions about the beginning of a tariff war between the United States and China, I thought it might be helpful to wade through some of the relevant issues. To summarize, I want to make the following major points:
- Trade deficits and surpluses typically force monetary and other economic changes in the affected countries that tend to eliminate the imbalances. The fact that many large economies have run substantial trade surpluses or deficits year after year, sometimes for decades, violates trade and economic logic; this pattern is evidence that mercantilist policy distortions, either in the surplus countries or in the deficit countries, are preventing trade from adjusting.
- The idea that all countries lose in a trade war is unintelligible. This cannot possibly be true, not just because there is overwhelming historical evidence that countries have benefitted from trade intervention but also because the claim is logically impossible. Whether countries benefit or lose from trade intervention depends on the underlying institutions that mediate trade and capital flows, the extent of existing trade and capital flow imbalances, and the types of intervention employed.
- While tariffs and other forms of trade intervention may indeed raise prices for consumers, this is only one way, and often a minor way, in which these policy tools affect households. Depending on underlying conditions, they may also reduce unemployment, cause wages to rise, and reduce the growth of debt.
- Tariffs and currency devaluation are not the only forms of trade intervention and are not the only ways distortions are introduced into global trade and capital flows. Any policy that alters the relationship between a country’s savings and its investment affects that country’s trade balance. Tariffs and currency devaluation affect trade balances not by changing the relative prices of tradable goods but rather by shifting income from households to businesses, thus forcing up the savings rate. Because of this, any policy aimed at making an economy more competitive internationally by suppressing wages is effectively a beggar-thy-neighbor policy. Any such policy works in exactly the same way as tariffs and currency devaluation.
- Because the relationship between U.S. investment and U.S. savings is determined externally, by the country’s role in absorbing excess global savings, tariffs and other beggar-thy-neighbor policies will not reduce U.S. trade deficits.
- In a globalized economy, it may be extremely difficult for any country to implement policies that protect the bargaining power of workers, that reverse income inequality, that raise minimum wages, that improve the social safety net, or that otherwise make households better off relative to businesses and governments. Implementing any of these policies causes a country’s international competitiveness to deteriorate. Consequently, rather than achieving the desired result, these policies cause the trade balance to go into deficit, and either unemployment will rise or debt must rise.
- To put it a little more starkly, a globalized economy must choose to protect its strength in the manufacturing and tradable sectors by lowering relative wages (directly or else indirectly in the form of tariffs, subsidies, or currency devaluation), or it must choose to boost the services and nontradable goods sectors through rapid debt growth.
How do tariffs affect prices?
There seems to be a basic assumption that there is a direct relationship between tariffs and the cost of goods to consumers. A 10 percent tariff on imported Chinese widgets, for instance, would be expected to raise the cost of widgets to consumers by 10 percent.
It almost never happens this way. Theoretically, the tariff is supposed to cause an upward shift in the supply curve because a smaller number of widgets can be produced for any given price. The new supply curve crosses the demand curve at a higher price, but almost never at a price higher by 10 percent. Figure 1 below shows how this happens.
Notice that tariffs have two adverse effects. First, the price of widgets is higher. Second, widget consumers buy and use fewer widgets than they otherwise would have. Widget consumers, in other words, are worse off in two ways: they use fewer widgets, and they must pay more for each one.
But it’s clear that the ways consumers are worse off must depend on the slopes of the supply and demand curves. A lot of this reasoning is fairly obvious and is much discussed in beginning economics textbooks, so I won’t write much more about this subject, except to make one important point: every single good against which tariffs are implemented will have its own supply and demand curves, making it impossible to make any general statement about how tariffs affect prices for consumers. In some cases, they might cause prices to rise by close to 10 percent. In other instances, they will have almost no impact on prices or on quantities purchased.
All of the reasoning above assumes that producer prices are fixed, but this is unlikely to be the case. In many instances, producers will respond to a tariff by lowering prices and reducing their profit margin. In such cases, the tariff is effectively paid for by producers in the form of lower profits, and consumers are able to buy as many widgets as ever at the same price as before. This tends to happen mainly with respect to high-value-added imports, in which case there is enough profit that the producer can cut prices; or in industries with large economies of scale or low marginal costs, in which producers want to protect sales volume; or in products that are considered strategically important and receive substantial direct or hidden government subsidies.
How are households affected overall by tariffs and other forms of trade intervention?
Most economists limit their discussions about the impact of tariffs and trade intervention to the impact on consumers. This is dishonest, or at best confused, because the primary impact of tariffs (and of trade intervention, generally) is not necessarily on consumption. Countries have successfully intervened in trade for centuries; yet mainstream economists often argue, against the evidence, that trade intervention is always harmful to the intervening country because it raises consumption prices.
But raising consumption prices is only one of the many ways that trade intervention can affect households. Trade intervention can also reduce unemployment, as it clearly did in the case of Germany after the Hartz labor reforms, which I discuss below. (Repressing wages, as I will show, has the same beggar-thy-neighbor impact on trade as devaluing the currency or imposing tariffs.) For similar reasons, trade intervention can affect households by allowing for domestic wage increases, as I explain in my most recent blog entry.
Trade intervention can also be used to allow for high-wage growth strategies. In a February 2017 blog entry, I discuss how the so-called American System of the nineteenth century, which included substantial trade protection, was designed in part to accommodate the fact that the United States had the highest wages in the world, and that these high wages themselves were the engine of productivity growth.
Trade intervention can also affect households directly or indirectly by slowing the growth in debt, whether consumer, government, or corporate debt. In reverse, this was shown by peripheral Europe before the 2008–2009 financial crisis, and has been shown by the United States over the past several decades; in both cases, these countries’ need to absorb trade intervention among their trading partners required rapid growth in debt. I have explained how this works many times before (here and here, for example). The basic argument in the case of the United States is that, because of its role as the absorber of excess global savings, the country has run a permanent capital account surplus since the 1970s, which is also why it has run a permanent current account deficit since then.
By definition, a capital account surplus—or its obverse, a current account deficit—means that a country’s investment must exceed savings, so that net foreign capital inflows must either increase investment or reduce savings. One hundred and fifty years ago, when U.S. investment was constrained by insufficient domestic savings, it would have increased investment, whereas today investment in advanced economies is not at all constrained by insufficient savings, so it must force down U.S. savings. There are many ways it does so, but these can be summarized as consisting basically of either a rise in unemployment or a rise in debt. For obvious reasons, the United States has almost always chosen the latter.
Limiting the discussion of the impact of U.S. tariffs on U.S. consumers is usually the result of either a very poor understanding of trade or a tendency to treat trade ideologically. I have often argued that U.S. President Donald Trump’s proposed tariffs on Chinese and other foreign goods will not reduce U.S. trade imbalances and are unlikely to be positive for the U.S. economy. But to oppose these tariffs on the grounds that they will raise the cost of consumption is silly. That is not why they will prove ineffective.
In fact, it is precisely because tariffs will have so small a net impact on the cost of consumption that they will not benefit the U.S. economy. If tariffs could successfully reduce the U.S. trade deficit, only then would they raise consumer costs. But in that case, even with higher consumer prices, American households would overall still be better off because they would more than make up for higher consumer prices with lower unemployment, higher wages, less income inequality, and/or less debt.
Why do countries intervene on trade?
I have argued many times that one of the major weaknesses of mainstream economics is the tendency of academic economists to substitute ideology for mathematical reasoning. They do this almost any time they argue that a particular policy or condition (trade intervention, supply-side policies, demand management, or free capital flows, among others) is abstractly “good” for the economy or “bad” for the economy.
As it happens, these policies can be positive for growth under certain conditions and negative under others, and there are several conditions under which trade intervention can be justified. To evaluate Trump’s tariffs and other forms of intervention, it is important to understand the conditions under which each of these will or will not succeed. These potential rationales include:
- The infant industry argument: This justification for protective intervention, based on Alexander Hamilton’s brilliant 1791 Report to the Congress, argues that certain industries, while internationally uncompetitive in their infant stages, can over the long run generate such rapid growth in productivity that they will eventually be able to compete internationally. In such cases, trade intervention is a strategy to allow them to survive in their early stages when they are not yet competitive.
- Industrial strategy: This approach is a more general version of the infant industry strategy and has been employed by governments—like the United States in the nineteenth century and China today—that want to shift a country’s economic structure in one direction or another, usually in the direction of manufacturing, high-tech sectors, or transportation. Industrial strategy often involves policies very similar to infant industry strategies and, to the extent that investment is funded domestically, it can involve policies that boost domestic savings, which I discuss below. For these reasons, industrial strategy tends to have a significant impact on generating trade imbalances, usually in the form of surpluses; that said, when industrial strategy is funded in part by foreign capital, as it was in the United States in the nineteenth century, it results in trade deficits.
- Boosting domestic savings: Countries that want to raise domestic savings, or that follow what I elsewhere have called a high-savings growth strategy, have implemented policies that force up savings rates in ways that inevitably generate trade surpluses. There are many policies that force up domestic savings, but they basically all work the same way: they transfer income from ordinary households, which consume most of their income, to sectors of the economy that consume little or none of their income. I discuss these policies more later in the blog post.
- Countering foreign trade intervention: There are often cases in which mercantilist or interventionist policies in one country create trade and capital flow imbalances that must be absorbed by another country, usually in the form of unwanted trade deficits. According to both economic and trade logic, large deficits or surpluses cannot persist over many years unless significant policy distortions keep them in place. This is because trade imbalances alter economic conditions, especially monetary conditions, in ways that automatically cause them to be reversed.
In other words, to the extent that imbalances have persisted for many years, or even decades, they must be sustained by policy distortions in either the surplus or the deficit country. In such cases, if a country is forced to absorb the distortions generated by another country, and it implements trade intervention policies aimed at reversing the effects of these distortions, these policies benefit both the first country and the global economy, although usually at the expense of the country where the distortions originated.
This has become an especially important argument in recent years. Distortions in the distribution of domestic income in several countries (most importantly, in China, Germany, and Japan) have led to huge savings imbalances, which are automatically absorbed by countries that have deep, flexible, and completely open capital markets with strong legal and governance institutions (mainly the United States and, to a lesser extent, the UK and other so-called Anglo-Saxon economies). The result has been that the former countries have run large, persistent surpluses for decades, while the latter have run large, persistent deficits. Policies among the trade-deficit countries aimed at reversing these imbalances can be justified as economically efficient and to the benefit of the deficit countries. - Boosting international competitiveness: There are basically two paths by which government reforms can make an economy more competitive internationally. The high road is to implement reforms that enhance worker productivity. Depending on how the benefits of greater productivity are shared with workers (usually in the form of higher wages), the reforming economy might run a trade surplus or a trade deficit. Either way, the global production of goods and services increases, as does global demand.
The low road is to reduce the household share of GDP in favor of producers, usually by directly or indirectly reducing wages. If a country reduces unit labor costs by lowering wages, its exporters can gain a greater global market share. Unfortunately, this strategy reduces consumption growth at home, and this effect is often exacerbated by a corresponding reduction in the growth of private sector investment (as occurred in Germany after the Hartz reforms). Nonetheless, the country implementing the reforms more than makes up for this decline in domestic demand, albeit at the expense of its trading partners, by gaining a greater share of global demand. This is a classic form of beggar-thy-neighbor policy. - Boosting domestic wages or reducing income inequality: The obverse to the above scenario is also true. Just as policies that reduce the household income share of GDP also boost international competitiveness, policies that do the opposite reduce international competitiveness. For this reason, in a truly globalized economy, it may be extremely difficult for any country to implement policies that protect the bargaining power of workers, that reverse income inequality, that raise minimum wages, that improve the social safety net, or that otherwise make households better off relative to businesses and governments. Implementing any of these policies, in other words, would cause a country’s international competitiveness to deteriorate. (As a related aside, a globalized economy also has more trouble absorbing immigrants because of the downward pressure on wages.)
This means that, rather than having their desired effect, policies aimed at improving the relative position of ordinary households might only cause the trade deficit to rise, as the demand impact of higher household income flows abroad. In such cases, a country must either face higher unemployment, or it must allow debt to rise fast enough to fund employment growth in the services and nontradable sectors of the economy to make up for the loss of jobs in the manufacturing and tradable goods sectors. To put it in starker terms, a globalized economy must choose either to protect its strength in the manufacturing and tradable-goods sectors by lowering relative wages (directly or indirectly, as I explain below) or to boost the services and nontradable-goods sectors while allowing rapid growth in debt.
How do tariffs affect a bilateral trade imbalance?
Tariffs can have a significant impact on the bilateral trade imbalance between two affected countries if they cause a reduction in imports from one of them. For example, if China is the main producer of widgets, and a 10 percent tariff on Chinese widgets causes the price of widgets in the United States to rise enough to prompt Americans to cut back sharply on widget consumption, then there would be a reduction in overall U.S. imports from China.
A tariff can also reduce the bilateral trade imbalance if it causes a shift in imports. A 10 percent tariff on Chinese widgets, for instance, might cause Chinese widget sales to collapse, to be replaced by a surge in Korean widget sales. If either of these two cases were to occur, Washington would almost certainly declare that its tariff policy was successful because it caused a significant improvement in the U.S. trade deficit, and the policy’s proponents would point to the lower U.S. trade deficit with China as proof.
But these two ways of reducing the U.S. deficit with China are not the same. In the first case, total U.S. imports would decline in line with the decline in U.S. imports from China, and the overall U.S. trade deficit would decline as well. In the second case, total U.S. imports were unaffected because the lower imports from China were matched by higher imports from Korea. In this case, there would simply be a shift in the structure of the U.S. trade deficit, but no change in the deficit itself.
How tariffs affect bilateral trade imbalances, in other words, doesn’t matter, even though most economists, journalists, and policymakers will judge the success or failure of tariffs on that basis. What matters, as I will explain below, is whether or not tariffs affect the relationship between domestic savings and domestic investment. In the case of the United States, they almost certainly will not affect this relationship because it is set externally and determined by net capital flows into the United States.
Do countries run trade surpluses because they produce cheaper or higher-quality goods than their trading partners?
No, that is not why they run trade surpluses. Despite the belief of many people, especially policymakers in trade-surplus countries, to the contrary, trade surpluses have nothing to do with how hard-working or efficient workers in the surplus country are. An April 2018 Financial Times article demonstrates just how absurd the belief can become:
Günther Oettinger, the EU’s budget commissioner, argued that the real reason for the EU’s persistent trade surplus with the US lay simply with US consumers and their appetite for European products. “The fact that Porsche, Audi, BMW and Mercedes-Benz, that those premium cars are selling like crazy in the US . . . has to do with design and motors, with quality. In contrast there is no real reason to bring an American car from the US to Germany.
At the beginning of the twenty-first century, Germany had been running more than a decade of trade deficits. Between 2003 and 2005, Berlin implemented what it called (a little euphemistically) the Hartz “labor reforms,” which aimed mainly at weakening German workers and reducing wages. Only after these reforms were implemented did Germany once again began to run trade surpluses, and these quickly ballooned into some of the largest trade surpluses in history.
Oettinger suggested that German trade surpluses are caused by the American love of high-end auto imports, but if that were true, it is hard to explain what happened before the Hartz reforms, when Germany ran trade deficits. Apparently, Oettinger thinks that Americans had never heard of German cars until 2005. This, of course, is just silly. In fact, trade surpluses and trade deficits are not the consequence of how efficiently and cheaply countries can produce tradable goods. It is the other way around. The relative price and efficiency with which countries can produce tradable goods is determined by their trade imbalances, which are themselves determined by their relative savings rates.
This is because a trade surplus (more accurately termed a current account surplus, but the difference doesn’t matter for the purposes of this discussion) is equal by definition to the excess of savings over investment. For that reason, any policy that leads savings to rise relative to investment must also result in an increase in a country’s trade surplus (or a decrease in its deficit). If, and only if, a country saves more than it invests, will it run a trade surplus.
This means that even if workers did start to work harder and more efficiently, that would not result in that country running a trade surplus. It is only if the workers are not paid sufficiently for their harder work that the country would begin to run a trade surplus.
But the same outcome results anyway whenever workers are paid a lower share of what they produce, whether or not they work harder. A country’s trade surplus is simply the consequence of households receiving an insufficiently high enough income to consume enough of the goods and services they produce (above the amount that is domestically invested). It has nothing to do with how efficiently those workers produce goods.
Are trade surpluses the result of domestic household prudence and thrift?
No, they are not. Along with the belief that trade surpluses are a reward for hard work, this is one of the most common misunderstandings about trade, and it is among the hardest to explain because the mistaken beliefs fit so well with common prejudices.
How much a country saves has very little to do with cultural propensities to save. It has mainly to do with the distribution of income domestically. All income on the supply side is by definition either saved or consumed (since saving just means not consuming), just as by definition all income on the demand side is either invested or consumed. This is why, in a closed system, savings is equal by definition to investment.
Whether income is consumed or saved depends largely on who receives it. It is worthwhile to think of a country consisting, broadly, of four groups: ordinary households, rich households, businesses, and governments. Ordinary households consume most of their income and save a small part of it. Rich households save most of their income and consume a small part of it. Businesses save all of their income (which they then either invest or pay out in dividends). Finally, governments consume a small part of their income (on behalf of households, for example, by providing healthcare or schooling) and save most of it.
Once it becomes clear that households are not the only, or even the main, source of a country’s savings, it is easy to see what determines a country’s overall savings rate. The greater the share of income that goes to ordinary households, the greater the consumption share is, and because all income that isn’t consumed is, by definition, saved, the lower the savings share is. Countries with large trade surpluses, driven by their high savings, are mainly countries in which ordinary households receive a lower share of GDP than they do in peer countries. This lower share of GDP determines the size of their trade surpluses.
It is not at all a coincidence that Germany began to run surpluses just when households began to retain a smaller share of what they produced. Contrary to Oettinger’s claims, Europe is not running a surplus with the United States because Americans for the first time discovered German cars. It is running a surplus with the United States because between 2003 and 2005, to reduce domestic unemployment, Germany implemented policies that reduced the share of income German workers received and caused business profits to soar. This effectively represented a transfer of wealth from ordinary households, which consume most of their income, to German businesses and their wealthy owners, who consume very little of their income. Consequently, the German consumption share of GDP declined. Sharply declining consumption shares are, of course, the obverse of sharply rising savings shares.
The Hartz reforms can be seen as a classic beggar-thy-neighbor policy that worked exactly as it is supposed to work. Rather than become more competitive by investing in productivity growth, Germany became more competitive by suppressing wage growth. As a result, Germany’s contribution to global demand declined (by the decline in the GDP share of consumption, sharply exacerbated by a decline in the GDP share of private-sector investment), but Berlin more than made up for this by taking a greater share of global demand. Germany’s soaring surpluses have nothing to do with the excellent cars Germany produces, the value of which had been well-known to Americans for decades.
For those who are interested, some of my earlier discussions on the source of trade imbalances and capital flow imbalances can be found here, here, here, and here.
Aren’t trade surpluses a reward for hard work and thrift?
Clearly, that is not the case. Aside from the fact that surpluses are structural and the result of distortions in the way income is distributed, there is no evidence that workers in surplus countries work more and are thriftier than workers in deficit countries, something that should be easy to prove if it were true.
The reasoning behind this thinking tends to be circular. When Germany ran deficits in the 1990s, German workers were widely criticized for their poor work habits. When the Hartz reforms were implemented and lower wage growth forced Germany into surplus, the same German workers whose poor work habits had been widely criticized were suddenly offered up as hard-working and prudent role models for the rest of Europe. This shift happened even though it turns out that German workers work substantially fewer hours every year than, for example, Spanish workers.
To the extent that households in some countries are indeed harder-working and thriftier than those in others—not just perceived as harder-working whenever structural income distortions cause their countries to run surpluses—those households will be rewarded not by trade surpluses but rather by the ability to import increasingly cheaper goods. The prize in trade, in other words, is the ability to import foreign goods and pay for them with fewer exports. Large persistent trade surpluses simply mean that workers are paid a very low share of what they produce.
If production-cost differentials don’t matter to the trade balance, how do tariffs work?
Tariffs shift income between different sectors of the economy and, in this way, change a country’s savings rate. This may seem at first counterintuitive, but it turns out that this process is reasonably clear and even obvious.
If Washington were to impose, for example, an effective 10 percent tariff on Chinese widgets, U.S. households would pay more for widgets. It turns out that this would affect the relative distribution of income in the United States. Assume that many U.S. households, perhaps all of them, would be directly or indirectly affected by the price of widgets; (if a given group of people didn’t directly buy widgets themselves, perhaps their local coffee shop would need widgets to serve them, in which case higher widget prices would be reflected in the price of their next cup of coffee). If the price of widgets were to rise, the real value of U.S. household income would decline—Americans would be able to buy fewer goods and services, in other words, for any given level of income.
On the other hand, other sectors of the economy—domestic widget producers, for example—would see the real value of their income rise. In net terms, tariffs on widgets would effectively represent a transfer of wealth from ordinary U.S. households (consumers) to other sectors of the economy (mainly businesses and, through dividend payments, their usually wealthy owners). This transfer of wealth from a high-consuming sector of the economy to a low-consuming sector automatically forces up the savings rate, and, as discussed above, if savings rise relative to investment, a country’s trade surplus rises or its deficit declines.
Why are tariffs and subsidies like currency devaluation and wage repression?
As I show above, tariffs alter a country’s trade balance not by changing relative prices, as is commonly supposed, but rather by shifting income. Any policy that effectively shifts household income to another sector of the economy, or that otherwise results in a smaller household income share of GDP, ultimately has a similar impact on a country’s trade balance by raising the savings rate and altering the relationship between savings and investment.
What may be surprising to many is that this dynamic is also exactly how lower wages, currency depreciation, and production subsidies (to the extent that they are ultimately paid for by transfers from the household sector) affect trade. These policies all effectively do the same thing: they improve a country’s so-called competitiveness by forcing down the real value of wages, which, in turn, reduces the household income share of GDP. As the share of GDP retained by ordinary households declines, the consumption share automatically falls too, which means, of course, that the savings share of GDP rises. If it rises relative to investment, it immediately causes an improvement in the trade balance.
In fact, this is one of the more conventionally surprising implications of trade analysis: in the end, imposing tariffs is no different than devaluing a currency or forcing down wages. And in economies for which investment is not constrained by low savings, all three methods are beggar-thy-neighbor trade policies that are done for the same reasons—to increase business profits and to reduce unemployment. These policies also have the same effects on trade partners: they weaken overall demand in the global economy by reducing the consumption share of GDP in the country that implements the policies. Consequently, that country benefits at the expense of its trading partners because that country’s policy choices allow it, through a greater trade surplus, to gain a larger share of remaining global demand.
Doesn’t that mean that tariffs always “work” to improve a trade imbalance?
No, it does not, and that is why it is important to understand how tariffs (or depressed wages or a devalued currency) actually affect trade balances. When one assumes that they work by altering relative costs—by making imports more expensive relative to domestically produced goods—then it is pretty easy to understand why they are likely to be successful. A 10 percent tariff on imported widgets would cause the price of foreign widgets to rise relative to domestically produced widgets, causing Americans to import fewer widgets and reducing the U.S. trade deficit.
But because tariffs only affect the trade balance to the extent that they alter the relationship between domestic savings and domestic investment, they work in some cases but don’t work in others. In the United States, it turns out, tariffs are unlikely to have an effect on the trade deficit because the relationship between domestic savings and domestic investment is determined not by domestic savings preferences but rather by foreign capital inflows. These foreign capital inflows are themselves determined by the need for foreigners to park their excess savings in a safe haven. I have discussed the reasons for this in the blog entries cited above.
Why are these beggar-thy-neighbor trade policies only in economies in which investment is not constrained by low savings?
Remember that imposing tariffs, devaluing a currency, and forcing down wages all have the same impact: all these methods transfer income from ordinary households, whether to businesses in the protected sector and to their wealthy owners (if tariffs are imposed), to the tradable goods sector (if the currency is devalued), or to labor-intensive businesses and the wealthy (if wages are repressed). In each case, income is transferred from the sector of the economy that consumes the highest share of its income and saves the lowest share to sectors that consume little or none of their income and save most or all of it. The net effect is an increase in the desired savings rate.
But savings don’t necessarily rise in every case. Because savings must equal investment in a closed economy, savings can only rise if investment rises; otherwise, some other event must occur that neutralizes the impact on savings that was set off by the shift in income from households to businesses and the wealthy.
In developing countries where desired investment levels are much higher than actual investment levels but constrained by high capital costs and the low availability of savings (most developing countries with the exception, mainly, of China), investment does rise. By transferring income from consumers to savers, these policies all result in higher investment, and the economy benefits from higher growth. Even though households suffer, their suffering is only temporary because the consequent increase in economic growth means that eventually they will earn more than they otherwise would have. This, in effect, is how trickle-down economics is supposed to work.
But in countries where desired investment levels don’t exceed actual investment levels and where the cost of capital is low and there is more than enough savings to satisfy the investment needs of businesses, trickle-down economics cannot work: transferring income from consumers to savers does not result in more investment. In fact, it may result in less investment to the extent that businesses react to lower consumption by investing less in the production of consumer goods. (This is what seems to have happened in Germany after the Hartz reforms, for example.)
This is where the problem lies: if consumption declines without a corresponding increase in investment, then something else must happen to counter the increase in desired savings (since savings can only increase if investment increases). There are three ways the resulting increase in desired savings can be balanced:
- The decline in demand must cause unemployment to rise, which leads savings to decline (since unemployed people have negative savings) by enough to neutralize the increase in savings caused by the shift in income.
- The decline in demand must be reversed by an increase in debt, which boosts demand and causes savings to decline (as debt is negative savings) by enough to neutralize the increase in savings caused by the shift in income.
- The excess savings must be exported, which means the country will run a trade surplus.
The third option, by the way, is not available to the United States or to other economies with very deep, open, and liquid capital markets and strong legal and governance institutions (like the UK and other Anglo-Saxon economies). That is because these economies do not control their capital accounts, and for this reason they in effect operate like closed economies. Since the 1970s, when excess global savings first became a problem, roughly 40–50 percent of the world’s excess savings have been parked in the United States. As a result, the United States has always run a capital account surplus that it cannot control and a corresponding current account deficit. This means that U.S. investment must always exceed U.S. savings by the amount at any point in time of net capital inflows.
One important, and perhaps surprising, implication is that the United States cannot engage in beggar-thy-neighbor policies because it cannot run a trade surplus. In fact, as long as its capital markets remain wholly open, it cannot even take steps to reduce its trade deficit except by making it harder, or less attractive, for investors to bring money into the United States. Because the U.S. trade deficit is set wholly by the net amount of excess foreign savings it has to absorb, it is not able to alter its overall savings rate.
Aside from this blog I write a monthly newsletter that covers some of the same topics covered on this blog. Those who are interested in receiving the newsletter should write to me at chinfinpettis @ yahoo.com, stating affiliation.
Comments(65)
"In fact, as long as its capital markets remain wholly open, it cannot even take steps to reduce its trade deficit except by making it harder, or less attractive, for investors to bring money into the United States." A little question here. If in a situation where USA defaults on its debt obligations, aka back in the Obama face off with the tea party, will that make it harder for investors to bring money to United States?
Moses Liao. I don't think it would make it any harder. But hey, if someone broke their word to you on money, You got less than you bargained for, only a fool would go back for more of the same. Right?
Yok, yes I was thinking since USA absorb half of the world savings, a default and a downgrade of the US bond ratings should push the savings away, That being said, US is the consumer of last resort, that may mean China has no choice but to continue to pour their savings in, even if the rating is junk
I'm not a financier, but I don't think it works that way. Rather, I think that lenders simply perform a glorified NPV calculation. If it looks like the overall debt is low enough that payments can be made on it, presumably people will still lend.
governments consume a small part of their income ... and save most of it.???
That got me too. I'm pretty sure governments save a small part and spend most of their income in addition to providing so called fiscal stabilizers such as the unemployment benefit.
I found that quite odd too, but note that the concept of government savings isn't the same as the budget deficit. Government savings equals current spending minus current income, while the budget deficit also includes capital expenditure and capital transfers. From a national accounting perspective, a government can be a net saver while still running a budget deficit.
The gov, as an entity itself, spend money on behalf of households. What the gov really consumes on behalf of itself is just a tiny portion of the total gov income (the expenses spent to keep the gov running as i understand). And whats not consumed is saved, or say invested.
It is immediately tempting to consider government income as only what it raises in taxes. Clearly governments often spend more than their tax receipts. But that deficit is always covered by the sale of government bonds (Treasuries, Gilts etc). The money raised by these sales is also government income.
The Budget Deficit that most governments run is the difference between the government's spending and income only from taxes and tariffs. That deficit never goes unfunded. The government also sells bonds e.g. Treasuries or Gilts. When considering what is the total of the government's income the receipts from the bond sales must be included.
I think this is less about altering trade policy for the U.S. on aggregate. I think this is more about preparing us to ramp up strategic sectors during wartime. Think Aluminum. Think Steel. What uses these two composite metals? What's an easy way to restrict population growth? What's an easy way to raise wages? Do tariffs stop with China? What happens if strong dollar is neutralized during full-employment? This adds up.
"... it cannot even take steps to reduce its trade deficit except by making it harder, or less attractive, for investors to bring money into the United States. " So perversely, the Fed, by tightening is trying to raise savings and reduce investment, all the while making treasuries more attractive as a store of value for global savings
I could be wrong, but I think one of the primary implications of Michael's post is that the Fed can't tighten in any practical sense so long as other countries are able to continue place money in the US.
Patel. I don't see things as you do. The fed is raising rates. Because of inflationary pressures. This increases the income of the wealthy. But the effect they want is that it squeezes out the financially weak and vulnerable, forcing businesses and individuals out of the economy, thus slowing the economy, bringing on a recession and an end to the inflationary pressures.
question: if the U.S. will run a trade deficit no matter what due to the desire of foreign entities to hold U.S. dollar investments, is it not a free lunch for the U.S. to implement a border tax or some sort of across the board tarriff as a way to raise large amounts of tax revenue from foreigners and thus address the deficit in a relatively pain free way?
Sorry Yuri, you display a lack of understanding of Mike's paper. Here it is: a tariff taxes the domestic household population, reducing their income.
The foreigners don't pay the tariff, the importers do. Interventionist policies that make others more competitive cause trade diversion. Trade creation occurs of comparative advantages when there are open markets, and not asymetries in policies between national markets. It is not foreigners paying taxes or tariffs, it is importers. So, the tariff will impact make versus buy, on-shore or off-shore, or off-shore other domicile decisions. Not cause foreigners to pay a tax. Unless there is a foreign corporation, in a tariff-able product category, who does work in US, and imports the product to US. Or imports, in such a product category, to a wholesale, or distribution network, in US.
governments consume a small part of their income ... and save most of it.???
Peter Scott. Yes. As an institution, the government is a big saver. Forget all the self serving lies put out there. What the government pays its' employees, which the employees then go out and spend as households. Well, that's the households. Right? When the government spends on say, a polio vaccine, that's an investment in my eyes. That's savings. Right? Cause in a closed economy Savings = Investment. The same holds true for all government supported research. The same is true for public education, roads, bridges, water and sewage treatment plants. I'm a little less satisfied with the military as savings, but hey how about all the defense related scientific research. Basic scientific research. You know, the kind that somehow leads to valuable things far afield. All the conservative attacks on government. Well most of them. I take them as pointed to the undermining of the democratic process. The wealthy and the powerful want the public to turn away from expecting and employing the government for the betterment of the community at large. They don't want the general population to use the government to promote the general welfare. Hence the attacks on social security, medicare, medicaid, snap, chip, uc, public education. They distrust a sense of community in the general population.
This all seems so logical and also seems to be an accurate reflection of reality. To me this means it should be possible to build a computational -graphical model. Steve Keen has done something like this that explores the effects of private debt vs public debt ratios on GDP growth. But it is, if not too complex, not at all compelling. What seems to be needed is perhaps an open source effort to construct a model based on agreed principles and a limited number of variables and "states" that can model passed events and has a predictive capacity. This should be a lot easier than weather and climate change. And perhaps more valuable. It needs to be recognized that the world is a closed system and has profound vulnerabilities. If we are headed for a global beggar thy neighbor scenario the formation of this situation should be plotted and the means of escape demonstrated in a compelling way.
Simon. Sorry. We'v been in a beggar scenario for quite a while now. You appear a little naive to me. Thinking that the leadership is sincerely looking for an understanding to improve the welfare of their country and citizens. Here's the truth: WHEN THE TRUTH RUNS AGAINST THE INTERESTS OF THE WEALTHY AND THE POWERFUL THE WEALTHY AND THE POWERFUL STEP ON THE TRUTH. The corruption economics. How about it. The Mystro. The top economist in the whole country. The largest and most destructive financial and economic event in 79 years. And he didn't see it coming and in fact contributed to it. And when we have telescopes that can see billions of light years out into space. How else do you understand that?
It seems to be true that the Oligarchy is a pretty stable political structure trending up while democracy is trending down(I think the US may be an Oligarchy). But that does not remove any interest in economic understanding. Even Oligarchs need to understand what's going on.
The US isn't even close to default and hasn't been close to default since the US Civil War. The issue for the World right now is that the World needs US trade more than US needs World trade. A sometimes painful renegotiation of almost every trade item is ongoing and will likely continue till the next World economic boom cycle gets into high gear. ouch. (wink) Unless you consider 9% or greater $USD inflation default.
At this time it looks like every $USD ($FRN) every created is trying to make its way back to the US. If this continues then every $USD denominated loan will have to be converted to local currency or be written-off. The Euro may be forced to be the reserve currency of the world. (joke) I predict Germany will leave the Euro if the Euro becomes the World reserve currency.
"making treasuries more attractive": Treasuries are entries in a data base of the US Treasury Department. Any country holding US Treasuries can be cut off by the US Congress at any time. (smile) That is why gold is so popular at this time.
Assume no workable policies can be reached to close open, very deep, and liquid capital markets of US, what if the following fiscal polices are implemented: 1) Border adjustment tax, peg to trade-deficit/total-trade ratio. It may causes currency devaluation and/or wage repression. But we don't want wage repression. So 2) Wage tax credit (obviously non-refundable), peg to 100% + trade-deficit/total-trade ratio. But we still have huge capital inflow from excess saving nations. So 3) Monetary asset sale tax, such as M&A, stock trading (exempt first 1m annually), second home, etc (bond is not a sale), paid by buyers (as in normal sale tax), progressive up to 300%. Hope it can steer extra saving from foreign nations toward the productive investment, instead of speculative investment. Will these fiscal polices somehow balance the trade and capital better than current policies?
One course of action would be to tax Chinese currency manipulation rather than Chinese exports. In order to undervalue the renminbi against the dollar, China drives the dollar's value up by buying dollar-denominated financial assets, principally U.S. Treasury bills and bonds. To discourage China from doing so, the U.S. government should tax the income on Chinese holdings of U.S. financial assets. For example, the U.S. Treasury would withhold tax on interest paid on Treasury bonds held by China. For every $10 billion of Treasury bond interest paid to the People's Bank of China (the central bank), the U.S. Treasury could withhold 30 percent, or $3 billion, in tax. By taxing the precise actions that cause distorted exchange rates, the United States would increase the incentive for China and other currency manipulators to allow the values of their currencies to reflect market fundamentals. An important benefit of this approach is that it would explode the myth, commonly held in China, that the United States wants or needs China to buy U.S. Treasury bonds. If China were to stop manipulating its currency, the dollar would decline against the renminbi, boosting U.S. exports and economic growth. If other currency manipulators -- such as Singapore and Taiwan -- do not absorb the implied lesson, their bilateral tax treaties with the United States could also be canceled and the amendment applied to them as well. Thanks to years of experience at combating money laundering and terrorist financing, which involves far smaller sums than the trillions of dollars that China has invested in U.S. financial assets, the U.S. Treasury Department should have no problem tracking and identifying any attempts at evasion.
Even though this paper primarily dealt China and US, to US its problem is not just trade deficit with China. So far, US has deficit $25b from China, $10b from Germany, $5b from Japan, $5b from South Korea, and $5b from others, monthly average. Michael mentioned many times the wage repression of Germany. So only valid approach is across board BAT.
Even though this paper primarily dealt China and US, to US its problem is not just trade deficit with China. So far, US has deficit $25b from China, $10b from Germany, $5b from Japan, $5b from South Korea, and $5b from others, monthly average. Michael mentioned many times the wage repression of Germany. So only valid approach is across board BAT.
Even though this paper primarily dealt China and US, to US its problem is not just trade deficit with China. So far, US has deficit $25b from China, $10b from Germany, $5b from Japan, $5b from South Korea, and $5b from others, monthly average. Michael mentioned many times the wage repression of Germany. So only valid approach is across board BAT.
Even though this paper primarily dealt China and US, to US its problem is not just trade deficit with China. So far, US has deficit $25b from China, $10b from Germany, $5b from Japan, $5b from South Korea, and $5b from others, monthly average. Michael mentioned many times the wage repression of Germany. So only valid approach is across board BAT.
VCR, I do not think that it is quite as simple as simply taxing Chinese currency manipulation rather than Chinese exports." If China were to revalue the RMB upwards but also expands credit and lowers interest rates, the wealth transferred from households to the tradeable goods sector would exceed the wealth transferred to the household sector via revaluation. This is in essence what Japan did after the 1985 Plaza Accords.
Thank you for this post. I remember reading your very similar arguments in The Great Rebalancing (Chapter 2?), but this argument seems so much clearer now. It does (as always) leave me with some questions, though: (1) Am I correct that the implication is that the US and UK are cursed, not blessed, by being home to the largest capital markets? Shouldn't the average American or Brit want Wall Street/the City to dry up and go over to, say, Germany or Singapore? (2) (And this one really confuses me...) Given your analysis, why are you in favour of saving the EU instead of its dissolution? It seems like Greece, Spain, Italy, etc would be better off by its abolition. Obviously you've already thought this through--I just can't connect the dots.
Claire. Hi. #1. The way I see it. There's nothing wrong with large, open capital markets - they'r good things. It's just that they get abused. Stop the abuse. Stop the abusers. I'm not Mike, but I think he's right. They should put in place capital controls, limiting the movement of currency into this country, or preferably taxing it. #2. I always understood Mike to be in favor of the European Union, the community of Europe, and also believing that the Euro, the EMU was ill-conceived and doomed to failure from the beginning.
Claire. Let me add this to @2. Mikes' thinking was the EMU was ill-conceived in not necessarily the idea of it, but how it was being implemented and administered.
Hi Yok! Thanks for the reply. Re: #1: I believe that capital controls would stop (or at least significantly slow down) the movement of currency into the US and GBR. In that case, wouldn't that in turn reduce the ability for the US and GBR to be the world's preeminent financial centers? (More to the point, wouldn't this be a good thing?) I ask this question largely because I never thought of it before--I always just assumed that there was an advantage to having Wall Street and the City. I'm now beginning to think that this advantage really only exists when a country needs to attract capital, and neither country has a scarcity of capital at the moment--rather, they have a scarcity of production caused by too much capital. Is this the correct interpretation?
Yok--Re#2: the EU--I guess that whether it was initially poorly implemented or not, it is difficult to see the creditor countries just accepting the previous EU without the Euro (actually, it's difficult to see the European creditor countries accepting anything other than the status quo, which is untenable). German policies may have been reckless, but German politicians aren't going to do anything that hastens their own banks to seize up and their own unemployment rates to shoot up significantly.
Hi Claire. Your questions get progressively more difficult. I'm not Mike, but I think "Yes, you'r right, capital controls, tax on incoming capital would reduce the activity on wall street." You'r right, we don't need more capital. The more freedom they have the more speculative they become. With greater wealth concentration and capital currency available and weak demand and lack of good investment opportunity, the lust for wealth and power gets the best of them and they gamble. I think the financial sector is very bloated and wasteful. The way I see it - they're long overdue for a trimming. Would of answered sooner but Mike didn't get your stuff from the 20th out till Aug 1.
Capital controls are the quickest way to derail an economy and send it into recession. I know I have lived through the period of capital controls in UK. They were imposed to stop capital flight when markets were rightly spooked by a socialist government. They had no success in promiting investment in domestic businesses and if capital did not leak out much, then profits earned abroad were left off-shore. When a subsequent government declared the intention of scrapping capital controls there were many people in the City, the Bank of England and the Treasury who were afraid there would be a rush to export money and a run on the pound. What happened instead was - money flowed in. This leads to the explanation. If you are contemplating moving your money to a destination for investment, the primary concern is, can you get it out again. If the answer is yes then you have eliminated that barrier. If the answer is no, then of course you do not invest. This is simply an extension of the basic truth, 'Money flows to where it is best treated.'
To qutoe Voltaire "common sense is not so common". Best post ever professor. Really should be required reading for policy makers everywhere.
"for the U.S. to implement a border tax or some sort of across the board tarriff as a way to raise large amounts of tax revenue from foreigners and thus address the deficit in a relatively pain free way?": That is what President Trump is threatening. Other countries think that solution is painful. The import sector of the US economy doesn't like it either. Tariffs were the way the US Government was mainly financed before the year 1913.
Ian S. "Capital Controls are the quickest way to derail an economy. " Yes, you made the point that if you try to keep domestic money in, it runs. But that's a straw dog. How about addressing Mike's point: BARRIERS TO KEEP FOREIGN MONEY OUT.
Yok. My first reply was to Claires question about the advisability of having capital controls. Now to your question about barriers to keep foreign money out - please read the last paragraph of Michael's article. It cannot be done in the US or UK. Apart from the impossibility, why would that be desirable? In the UK the majority of manufacturing industry and several service business are majority owned by foreign corporations. But British capital thus released from domestic assets has taken a minority share in nearly every successful company in the world. 'Balance of payments' here cannot be defined or even encompassed because the boundary of what is the UK economy certainly isn't our territorial waters.
Ian S. I read the last paragraph in Mike's article. I suggest to you that you re-read it; you'r not understanding him correctly. "In fact, as long as it's capital markets remain wholly open, it cannot even take steps to reduce its trade deficit except by making it harder, or less attractive, for investors to bring money into the United States." I understand him to be saying being "wholly open" is a vulnerability. Hey, we don't even do soft controls by using red tape, fees, time, taxes, say like the Chinese do. Of course we do have some tariffs and controls, but speaking in a general sense. Mike has made this point several times before, and we have used capital controls before. You are making false associations - holding in is the exact opposite of holding out. Right? So we might expect opposite reactions from the public. Right? Also too, implied within your post is the idea foreign money coming in is a blessing - wrong. Unless the foreign money is accompanied by new technology or managerial expertise, the net effect is harm to the country. You imply that a developed, rich country is solely dependent on private investment for growth - wrong. You say a socialist government is bad - that's another false association. All governments, to the extent that they promote the welfare of the general public are socialist. A republican, what they call a democratic government, is in fact, of a socialist nature. Socialism - to place under the control, responsibility, authority, or ownership of the public, where the public can be considered to exert, or have meaningful control. The so-called western democracies were in fact more socialist than the Soviet Union.
Only one small typo: In paragraph titled: Doesn’t that mean that tariffs... at the end of fourth line the phrase "than it is" shuld read "then it is"
@Giancarlo thanks for catching that! We have corrected it.
Peter Scott. Yes. Governments save like crazy. Think of the government and households as institutions.
Are you saying there is no realization in the US administration that, to effectively close the US trade deficit, the monetary side of international trade needs to be addressed, ie. the international status of the USD as international reserve currency needs to be revoked to be replaced with a supranational unit of account which is not also the domestic currency of a participating country? I would find this hard to believe.
Well, the US administration is not a single individual, and in any case it has competing objectives. The US benefits politically internationally by having the reserve currency (or at least it believes it does). The question is whether the drag on the domestic economy is worth the political benefits they receive internationally. Immediately after WWII, the overwhelming consensus was that the price was worth paying; now the overwhelming consensus may reverse.
"Will these fiscal polices somehow balance the trade and capital better than current policies?" : Doubtful even one of these intriguing ideas could be implemented at this time. Might have been possible ten years ago. Current US policies are making $USD unpopular as a reserve currency. With backing from IMF and BIS a cryptocurrency could replace a reserve currency for trade. UN Security Council would have to sign-off also. Not likely to happen either.
Re: Current US policies are making $USD unpopular as a reserve currency-->I think you might be missing the point that there is no viable alternative to the USD as a reserve currency because no other country is willing to accept such a status due to the economic implications. Other countries do not buy $USD because they lover or hate the US--they buy it in order to beggar their neighbours.
The IMF comment is a little strange. Firstly, the US has a veto. Secondly, why would any country other than the US want to end the USD status as a reserve currency?
Do not publish as comment, just correct the typo: Sub par. "Doesn’t that mean that tariffs always “work” to improve a trade imbalance?" end of fourth line "than it is" should be "then it is" (with an e)
"Remember that imposing tariffs, devaluing a currency, and forcing down wages all have the same impact: all these methods transfer income from ordinary households..." What would happen if the U.S. government distributed all its tariff income directly to ordinary American households? Could be done very simply, the way the Alaskan Permanent Fund distributes money to Alaskan residents.
Firstly, I'm having trouble understanding the causality and relationship between government spending and current account deficits. Specifically, what percentage of U.S. government trade deficit is determined by a.) fiscal deficits and b.) mercantilist export promotion policies of China, Japan, Korea, and Germany. If (Imports - Exports) = (Investment - Savings) + (Government Spending - Tax Revenue), it is easy to see how mercantilist policies in foreign countries force savings up and affect the trade account of trading partners. However, it isn't intuitive to me how this relationship works for the US's fiscal deficits and causality in the function. I would appreciate help thinking about this or reference to further reading. Secondly, excellent post Michael. I thoroughly enjoyed the reading. Thank you for the insight this blog brings.
Disregard my question. I found Michael's post from 2017 on the topic.
" IMF comment is a little strange": Sorry for being unclear. My reasoning is that SDR is expected to be reserve currency at some unspecified future date. Could be in this century if US tariffs are raised high enough. Current US administration would probably be ok with world replacing $USD with SDR. IMF has a gold reserve for some unknown reason (at least to me). To back SDR if some members are recalcitrant? To cover non-performing-loans?
"paying attention to Prof. Pettis's arguments":Page 29 of "The Great Rebalancing" : "...If the tariffs caused Fredonian real household income to decline...". That is the question. (I think) World leaders don't think US imposed tariffs will cause household incomes in the US to decline. If household incomes in the US did decline then the idea of distributing US imposed tariff income to US households might be accepted.
"distributed all its tariff income directly to ordinary American households?": Would make tariffs very popular with the average voter collecting a payment. Importers do not want a tariff. Works like a sales tax to them.
Hugs - But more to the point, would it not be a perfect way to strengthen the U.S. economy? If the basic problem with the world economy is insufficient spending power in the hands of consumers, then redistributing money to U.S. consumers (the poor and middle class, the rich don't spend much) should help the world economy. Using tariffs to raise the money to redistribute to consumers has the potential to keep the jobs benefit in the U.S. instead of letting it go to China and elsewhere. Right?
"the basic problem with the world economy": Current belief in leadership is that the world has too much monetary capital. The current economic disputes are over market share and who gets to deploy monetary capital. In the US the poor have issues that have nothing to do with an economy. In a poor country the US poor would be forced to change their behavior. Randy Quaid the actor is an example.
Hugs, with all due respect I'm not sure whether you have been paying attention to Prof. Pettis's arguments or whether you simply disagree with them. His arguments have nothing to do with whether the poor (or anyone else for that matter) are morally deficient. He simply believes that anything that redistributes buying power to entities that will USE it (to buy goods and services, not to hoard or invest it) is good for the world economy as it is today. Anything that does the opposite is bad for the economy. Not forever and for always, but now, given the way the economy is today.
Yok. Your definition of Socialism stating 'taking under the control of the Public' is what it might say in the manifesto. In fact it is taking it into the control of the State. Socialist governments do everything in their power to stop the Public having a say in the running of the enterprise, or removing them as the managers. This is based on Envy - see Helmut Schoek and the Fatal Conceit see Hayek. Cuba, Zimbabwe, Venezuela, QED. There isn't any difference in the effect of imposing a block on money coming in, or imposing it on money leaving. The fact is that money is prevented from circulating by either block and it soon departs for better places.
Karen, I'm just saying that leaders don't think that US consumption needs to increase and that leaders don't think US consumption will fall because of tariffs by a significant amount. That is why US tariffs are viewed so negatively by the world.
Ian S. Your head is filled with a lot of Dogma. The people who lust for wealth and power - they hate democracy. They don't like republicanism. They always look for a facade. Socialism - it's about loving your country, your community, your neighbors. It's the soil out of which comes patriots. Your examples of socialism failure - false associations. I don't know that Zimbabwe even considered itself socialist. How about these examples of socialism: Denmark, Sweden, Norway. Socialism, it's about people looking to their own well being and welfare through the institution of government. Representative government is an example of socialism. Social Security - socialism. US Army - Socialism. Medicare - socialism. Public Schools - socialism. The police - socialism. Public Water and Sewage - socialism. Your heads full of nonsense. The wealthy and the powerful - they don't want their hands tied. They want complete freedom to use their wealth and power to their advantage. The greed and selfishness of the wealthy and the powerful is a burden to the general welfare. It' how we get wars of aggression and subjugation. But hey, to your way of thinking, the wealthy and the powerful are blessing to humanity wherever they go. We better kiss their &*$ or they'll pick up their marbles and go somewhere else.
Comment Policy
Comments that include profanity, personal attacks, or other inappropriate material will be removed. Additionally, entries that are unsigned or contain "signatures" by someone other than the actual author will be removed. Finally, steps will be taken to block users who violate any of the posting standards, terms of use, privacy policies, or any other policies governing this site. You are fully responsible for the content that you post.