Source: The Financial Times
The angry statements about currency manipulation continue, with anger focused on China’s renminbi. It is not the only country to intervene, but the scale of its action and the size of its trade surplus make it an obvious target. An excessive focus on the renminbi will soon make a bad situation worse, however, especially for China. As Premier Wen Jiabao’s testy statement last week in Europe revealed, for all its growth, China’s economy remains unbalanced and vulnerable to deterioration in its trade account.
There are many ways for China to rebalance, although all involve transferring income from producers to households, so the latter can increase their share of consumption. Raising the value of the renminbi increases household income by reducing the cost of imports, although it also lowers the profitability of exports. The result, if done carefully, should nonetheless see the household share of China’s gross domestic product rise, and with it consumption. Since more of what China produces is then consumed domestically, China’s trade surplus should fall too.
But what would happen if China raised its currency too quickly, as most of its trading partners want and as Mr Wen warned against? In that case, the profitability of the export sector would decline so quickly that exporters would be forced either into bankruptcy or into lower-wage countries. They would fire workers, who would then consume less. So China faces a choice: rebalance speedily with high unemployment, or slowly with low unemployment.
That is why too much focus on the currency is dangerous. It is clear that the US and other countries have become impatient with China’s slow adjustment. Every large world economy, including China, is implicitly expecting US consumption to drive employment growth, as Mr Wen all but told President Barack Obama in New York in late September.
However, with soaring unemployment at home, the US is in no mood to divert more of its demand abroad. America wants to boost its own exports, and there is a good chance that it will now overreact to Chinese foot-dragging and use the threat of tariffs to force a faster appreciation than China can afford.
In that case, what will Beijing do? Most probably, as Japan did after the 1985 Plaza Accords and Beijing itself did after the renminbi began appreciating in 2005, it will lower real interest rates and force a surge in investment by expanding credit rapidly. This will unwind the unemployment rise caused by renminbi appreciation: as manufacturers in the tradable goods lose competitiveness others will enjoy lower financing costs. But there will be a high price to pay.
Revaluation will divert income from exporters to households, as it should, but the response will then shift income from households (who provide most of the country’s net savings) to large borrowers with access to bank credit. China won’t really rebalance, which requires a permanent increase in the household share of GDP. Instead the country’s overdependence on exports will be reduced, but its even greater overdependence on investment will increase. Textile producers and toy manufacturers will shed jobs, while shipbuilders and steel producers will expand.
This would be terrible for China. Lower interest rates and more credit will fuel a real estate boom, and boost both capital-intensive manufacturing and infrastructure overcapacity – all without rebalanced consumption. It will also increase pressure on the likes of Japan and South Korea, which rely on capital-intensive industries. China, and surplus countries such as Germany and Japan, must understand that their policies damage the rest of the world. But the world also needs to understand that these countries cannot adjust quickly without damaging internal consequences.
Any solution will therefore require statesman-like behaviour, in which the major economies agree to resolve their trade imbalances over several years. But periods of global economic contraction and rising unemployment do not usually welcome statesmen. Sadly, it is much more likely that trade relations will continue to deteriorate, and the longer surplus countries drag their heels the more attitudes will harden. In that case, China’s overinvestment problem is certain to become even worse.