in the media

Beijing's Currency Choice

Beijing should focus more on individual market reforms and worry less about internationalizing the yuan.

published by
Wall Street Journal
 on December 4, 2012

Source: Wall Street Journal

Four centuries ago, at the height of China's global trade reach, Chinese copper coins were used as an international medium of exchange throughout Asia and beyond. Today, with ongoing economic problems in the West and China's relatively strong performance, many economic observers forecast China's return to monetary prominence in the form of yuan internationalization.

Such talk is far from idle chatter. Amid the re-emergence of China as the world's second largest economy—not to mention fulcrum of the world's most dynamic trading region—Beijing has taken a series of steps to promote yuan internationalization. It has introduced currency swaps with some dozen countries, liberalized entry for foreign investors and use of yuan-denominated funds in Hong Kong, and permitted limited participation of foreign central banks in the domestic interbank market.

Surprisingly, though, the avalanche of discussion on the yuan has focused mostly on what China should do. Few ask why China is doing this at all.

From Beijing's perspective, the benefits from internationalizing its currency are not obvious. China's pragmatic leadership has historically placed a high value on maintaining economic stability. But currency internationalization and accompanying financial liberalization will inevitably lead to greater volatility as policy makers relax controls over capital movements as well as over interest and exchange rates.

In turn, policy makers will be forced to sacrifice some control over monetary policy, because pressures to maintain the yuan's value and availability as a global currency may conflict with domestic needs. An international currency historically requires expanding its supply abroad by running large budget or current-account deficits—both of which are anathema to Beijing. These costs help explain why in the past, Japan and Germany both opposed internationalizing their currencies.

So why is China considering it? Some suggest that higher seigniorage—the profit made by selling one's currency—as well as the benefit of pricing imports in your own currency (and avoiding balance-of-payments crises) is attractive to China. But China has vehemently criticized the U.S. in the past for taking advantage of this "exorbitant privilege."

Others have suggested that the push to internationalize the yuan is a form of "reform by Trojan horse." To wit, China's reformers see currency internationalization not as an end goal, but as a pretext to push for more market reforms. There is logic in this argument, since internationalization demands improving China's rudimentary financial markets and gutting its capital controls.

Let's understand what these reforms really are. If we delve into them, we find that they are useful for their own sake, and not just as preconditions for yuan internationalization:

  • Liberalizing exchange rates. Several years of steady appreciation means that the yuan is near its equilibrium level. With the dollar and euro more volatile and China's trade prospects deteriorating, there is no clear pressure for the yuan to move either up or down. Now is a good time for China to expand the yuan trading band, furthering the goal of making the currency more responsive to market signals.
     
  • Relaxing capital controls. Capital account liberalization is frequently mentioned as a stumbling block in the reform process, because it means capital can escape China. Already, some have raised alarm bells about "capital flight" from China over the past year. However, China's comfortable $3.2 trillion reserve cushion, high domestic savings, and relatively high growth prospects decrease this risk.

    In fact, allowing more capital outflows has several benefits for China. These include diversifying investment options for Chinese firms and households away from domestic property markets and away from risky speculation in shadow-banking products. Allowing capital to flow abroad would also introduce more competition into domestic financial markets, which would facilitate its development..
     
  • Liberalizing interest rates. This reform is less achievable in the near term. Without well-developed capital markets, there is no realistic way to establish true market-driven interest rates in China. Controlled rates will likely continue as long as the government continues to use its state banks as quasi-fiscal instruments to channel resources, while neglecting the need to strengthen its fiscal system for this purpose.

These initiatives will take time and energy. For the time being, Beijing should focus more on these individual reforms and worry less about internationalizing the yuan as a longer-term objective. There is one area, though, where some experiments in promoting yuan usage could generate near-term benefits and offer lessons for the future. And that's regional trade.

Nearly half of China's trade is processing-related—that is, trade comprising parts and components from other East Asian countries that are assembled in China for export to the West. Currencies of several Asian countries already track the yuan more closely than the dollar, which means the yuan could be used as a "reference currency" for the East Asian production-sharing network.

China and, more generally, Asia would benefit from greater use of the yuan to improve trade efficiency, lower transaction costs and reduce exchange-rate risk in intra-Asian trade. But there's a bigger lesson too.

China runs significant trade deficits with most of its Asian partners, which is to say the yuan is in demand across Asia. That means coordinating Asian currencies has near-term potential to increase use of the yuan as a settlement currency and even as a regional reserve currency, in much the same way that America's trade deficits help the dollar's status as the global reserve. In this way, the changing role of the yuan in the Asian trading bloc will provide a useful opportunity to preview the tangible effects of fuller yuan internationalization.

This article was originally published in the Wall Street Journal.

Carnegie does not take institutional positions on public policy issues; the views represented herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of Carnegie, its staff, or its trustees.