Registration
You will receive an email confirming your registration.
On Wednesday, April 17 Professor Alexander A. Dynkin spoke about "Russia's Big Conglomerates and the Country's Modernization." Professor Dynkin is First Deputy Director of the Institute of the World Economy and International Relations (IMEMO) and corresponding member of the Russian Academy of Sciences. He has worked as an economic advisor to former Prime Minister Yevgeny Primakov and former Deputy Prime Minister Boris Fedorov.
Russia is a country dominated by 15-20 big conglomerates. Professor Dynkin
recently completed a study of these conglomerates and their effect on the Russian
economy. Professor Dynkin examined 738 enterprises belonging to 8 different
Integrated Business Groups (IBG). Each IBG was selected for the study on the
basis of five formal statistical criteria - output volume, reported profits,
number of staff, market value and volume of exports - and various informal criteria
such as cross ownership of property and friendly relations between top managers.
Russia's large state-owned natural monopolies like Gazprom and RAO UES were
purposely excluded from the study. The 8 IBGs that were selected were LUKoil,
Yukos, Interros, Surgutneftegaz, Alfa Group-Renova, Sibirski Aluminy-Sibneft,
Severstal and Sistema. Together these 8 businesses account for 15% of Russia's
total output of goods and services and over 32% of Russia's industrial output.
Each of these IBGs share common structural elements. Within each IBG there exists
a core group of manufacturing and banking enterprises surrounded by a wide web
of financial institutions, building companies, transport companies, mass media
outlets and even health and recreation centers. According to Dynkin, this vast
hodgepodge of enterprises that reside within one IBG is a natural reaction to
the system of centralized economic planning out of which these conglomerates
emerged. In form, these Russian IBGs are similar to other large chaebol like
companies that have taken root in countries as diverse as India, Brazil and
Chile. In the early 20th century, the United States itself had similar types
of business. The Ford Motor Company of 1927 really was not all that different
from the Russian IBGs of today.
Recently, various trends in the development of Russia's IBGs have begun to emerge.
Most notably, these companies have begun to shift the focus of their activities
from simple resource extraction to higher value-added sectors of the economy.
Both Interros and Sistema have moved aggressively into communications and electronics,
while Sibirski Aluminy-Sibneft and Severstal have started to develop enterprises
in the engineering industry. All 8 of the IBGs studied by Professor Dynkin appear
to have weathered the 1998 financial storm intact and have steadily increased
their share of tax revenues, to over 25% of state revenues for 2000, their share
of exports, to over 25% of Russia's total volume of exports for 2000, and the
level of their long-term investments in the Russian economy. Concomitantly,
Russia's IBGs have expanded their activities in Russia's regions, opening numerous
regional branches and acquiring local enterprises. Most IBG activity is focused
in Russia's central federal district, but large gains have been made in the
Privolzhski, Siberian, Ural and NorthWestern districts as well. Thus, these
IBGs are well poised to continue in their roles as major investors in the Russian
economy for the next 5-7 years.
Overall, the growth of IBGs has had many positive benefits for the Russian economy.
IBGs have been instrumental in adapting Russian big industry to the market economy.
They have cut transaction expenses and helped mediate between individual companies
and imperfect markets. They have effectively concentrated highly qualified human
capital where it has been most in demand and have taken technological and financial
risks, helping to bring innovative new products to the market. Moreover, IBGs
have been crucial in mediating between the interests of their own enterprises
and those of foreign partners and the authorities.
In light of these positive developments, Professor Dynkin proposes more active
state support for IBGs. A number of measures including state subsidization of
interest rates on merger & acquisition financing, transferring state-owned
stock to trust managements and converting enterprises' tax debt into stock for
sale to strategic owners would help these companies. Overall, the development
of Russia's IBGs should be guided by joint decision making between state and
business representatives. Consultations with industry associations should be
encouraged through the Ministry of Economy, while a place should also be made
for consulting firms and PR-agencies to voice their opinions to ensure that
numerous actors can provide input in government to business relations.
In the future, Professor Dynkin believes that there are three possible ways
for Russia's big conglomerates to develop. The first and most likely scenario
would be the corporatization of these IBGs with their transformation into public
highly-diversified industrial corporations, supplying a wide range of products
and services. In the second scenario, these IBGs would consolidate their positions
through leveraged buy-outs, selling part of their non-core assets while forming
a core business group. The third possible scenario would be the complete disintegration
of Russian IBGs resulting from a 'managers' revolution', whereby enterprise
managers would seize the stock of profitable companies and force the owners
to hand over the controlling stock.
Whatever the future may hold for Russia's IBGs, they remain, in Professor Dynkin's
eyes, the key to ensuring investment in the Russian economy. It may be true
that big conglomerates hamper the growth of small business, have a dubious impact
on the strength of democracy and do not always ensure a proper allocation of
resources, but given historical circumstances Russia simply has no other choice
in its development strategy. Russia's banking sector is far too small and the
capitalization of its stock market is too low to adequately meet the investment
needs of the country. As long as foreign investors remain wary of Russia's notorious
pitfalls, IBGs will remain the only resource available for financing Russia's
continued growth.
Summary by Karlis Kirsis, Junior Fellow, Russian & Eurasian Program.