Source: Getty

Lebanon’s Political Economy: From Predatory to Self-Devouring

To survive its ongoing financial crisis, Lebanon needs a new economic system that addresses massive income inequality. Paired with political and institutional reform, tax reform can help.

Published on January 14, 2021

Summary

Over the past three decades, Lebanon’s ruling class—which comprises intertwined political and business elites—has run the country into the ground. To survive its ongoing accumulation of challenges, including the financial crisis that erupted in October 2019, Lebanon requires a revamped state backed by a new economic model with social justice at its core. Tax reform is central to such an endeavor—and to ensuring that the state has the means both to deliver basic services and to tackle poverty and inequality.

Key Themes

  • Since 2005, Lebanon has been characterized by extreme inequality in both income and wealth. The richest 1 percent of the population receives, on average, 25 percent of national income, while the poorest half receives less than 10 percent. Regarding wealth, the richest 10 percent of the population owns almost 70 percent of total wealth. Additionally, the middle class and the poor have little chance of upward mobility.
  • Those responsible for this situation are the country’s political and business elites. Together, they have divided the country’s public and private sectors between themselves and created a system in which they can extract rent on virtually any economic activity.
  • Without radical and immediate reforms, Lebanon will become a failed state. Though major political and institutional change is necessary, redesigning the country’s economic model is no less urgent. The key to designing such a model as well as a new state guaranteeing a fairer distribution of resources is fiscal reform.

Findings and Recommendations

  • Lebanon should design a general and progressive income tax, one that taxes all sources of income together, as opposed to separately. This would include all types of capital income.
  • Lebanon should increase top marginal tax rates applied to the highest incomes. Top marginal tax rates in Lebanon are quite low by international and historical standards.
  • Lebanon should institute a one-time wealth tax on the richest Lebanese for the purpose of funding much-needed emergency relief: an exceptional 10 percent tax on billionaires would yield 2-3 percent of the national income, which is more than what the progressive income tax currently collects from all Lebanese combined.
  • Over and above the one-time wealth tax, it is essential that Lebanon levy an annual tax on wealth in all its forms, in particular on built property, in order to increase revenue.

Introduction

Even before the massive protests that shook Lebanon in October 2019, the country’s political economy was fraying.1 Yet the inevitable and ongoing financial collapse has taken many by surprise, owing to the widespread assumption that Lebanon’s consociational democracy and laissez-faire economy—rooted in the banking and real estate sectors—was both exceptional and durable. The country’s political elite had long amplified this trope of Lebanese exceptionalism in order to maintain a status quoof which it was the prime if not exclusive beneficiary. The truth, however, is that Lebanon’s exceptionalism lies in its record-high income and wealth inequality, which is perpetuated by a corrupt political economy. In fact, it was precisely such exceptionalism that served as the main driver of the 2019 protests.2

Earlier that year, the Lebanese government had discussed launching an austerity program to deal with a brewing financial crisis. The poorest and most vulnerable segments of the population would have been disproportionately affected by a raft of ill-thought measures: cuts in public sector wages, monthly salaries, and pensions; a hike in taxes on imported products; and decreased funding for nongovernmental organizations, many of which cater to the disadvantaged. On October 17, 2019, the government complicated matters by announcing two new measures—a twenty-cent daily fee on Internet phone calls, including on the widely used WhatsApp application, and a plan to increase the value-added tax from 11 to 15 percent by 2022.3 This was the last straw. Lebanese took to the streets en masse to call for an end to a corrupt political system that denied them economic opportunities and enabled the intertwined ruling and business elites to continue enriching themselves.

In 2020, with the devaluation of the Lebanese pound brought about by the now full-blown financial crisis, the economy went into free fall and the share of the population in dire straits ballooned.4 In June 2020, outgoing economy minister Raoul Nehme announced that 60 percent of Lebanese would find themselves below the poverty line by the end of the year.5 That same month, the head of the Beirut Traders Association revealed that a quarter of Beirut’s private sector businesses had closed, with the figure even higher outside the capital. He predicted that the trend would continue.6 In July 2020, the price of food items and non-alcoholic beverages increased by 24 percent compared to the previous month and by more than 330 percent compared to July 2019.7

Human Rights Watch has warned that millions of people in the country are at risk of famine.8 Among poor Lebanese, suicides due to insolvency and desperation have surged.9 Meanwhile, domestic migrant workers, already subject to the exploitative kafala (sponsorship) system and often living in appalling conditions, are increasingly abandoned outside their countries’ embassies by “sponsors” who can no longer afford to pay them.10 The COVID-19 crisis accelerated Lebanon’s implosion and further harmed the country’s most vulnerable sectors of the population. And then, on August 4, the Beirut Port explosion brought the country to its knees.

Lebanon stands in dire need of a bailout by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), which has signaled its willingness to help. However, the IMF attached conditions to its proposed aid package: Lebanon would have to enact structural reforms that increase transparency and financial stability as well as reduce corruption and tax evasion.11 Unsurprisingly, the country’s ruling class has proven unwilling to meet such demands for fear of losing its privileges. As a result, the meetings Lebanese governmental delegations have held with IMF officials have ground to a standstill.12

Nevertheless, if anything, the ongoing collapse of Lebanon’s financial sector presents Lebanese with an opportunity to revamp their country’s inherently unsound political economy. While such an overhaul would entail radical political change, including the dismantlement of the sectarian power-sharing system, it should also introduce a redesigned Lebanese economic model, one that moves away from neoliberalism and toward a centralized welfare state.13 Given Lebanon’s extreme levels of poverty and inequality and the shriveling of its middle class, the new economic model must have social justice at its core. In a country where the state raises little revenue and fails to guarantee social justice, tax reform should be a building block of any reform package and of a revamped Lebanese state.

A Country of Extreme Income and Wealth Inequality

Income disparity is endemic to Lebanon. The first countrywide study of Lebanese income distribution took place in 1960 and revealed that the richest 4 percent of the population earned 32 percent of the national income. Half the population lived in poverty, earning only 18 percent of national income.14 There were even significant disparities between the two groups falling between the richest 4 percent and the bottom 50 percent.15

Little has changed in the intervening six decades. A study published in 2018 by the World Inequality Lab used micro-fiscal data to estimate income distribution for the entire population of Lebanon between 2005 and 2016, including non-Lebanese migrant workers and refugees.16 The figures are startling. The top 10 percent of the country’s richest individuals earned between 49 and 54 percent of national income, the middle 40 percent earned 34 percent, and the poorest 50 percent of the population earned between 12 and 14 percent (see figure 1). As a yearly average, the richest 10 percent pocketed more than 50 percent of all income earned in the country. By comparison, this figure stood under 35 percent in France and around 45 percent in the United States. Such a statistic places Lebanon among the countries with the highest levels of income inequality in the world, alongside South Africa and Brazil (see figure 2).

Besides, there has been little upward mobility for the middle class and the poor. Between 2005 and 2016, the probability of staying in the richest 1 percent income category the following year was, on average, 75 percent. For the top 0.1 percent, the probability of remaining in the group was about 70 percent. The same applied to the probability of staying in top groups after two or three years (see figures 3a and 3b). These figures were high when compared to those of other countries, such as Canada and the United States.17

A similarly alarming situation becomes apparent when looking at only the labor income distribution (meaning wages, salaries, and pensions), the type of income that the majority of the population earns.18 The data indicate that the top 10 percent of labor income earners received between 41 and 45 percent of total labor income (see figure 4). The poorest 50 percent received between 13 and 15 percent of the total share, which is almost the same as the share earned by the richest 1 percent (see figure 5). Interestingly, between 2005 and 2016, the fiscal data only cover between 4 and 13 percent of the total labor force. In other words, the fiscal administration covers only a small share of the total labor force, suggesting that the informal sector’s share is very large and probably larger than official estimates.19

Wealth inequality in the country also appears to be extreme, although it is trickier to estimate as wealth data are scarcer than income data in Lebanon. Only two sources are currently available to track wealth ownership in Lebanon: the distribution of bank deposits in 2017 and billionaires’ lists published by two magazines, Forbes and Arabian Business. According to the former source, 0.1 percent of bank accounts made up 20 percent of all deposits.20 According to both Forbes and Arabian Business, billionaires’ wealth represented, on average, 30 percent of total national income in Lebanon between 1990 and 2016, and 23 percent between 2010–2017, surpassing by far most other countries’ figures (see figure 6). Between 1990 and 2016, 10 percent of the population owned nearly 70 percent of the country’s total wealth, 1 percent owned close to 45 percent, and the poorest 50 percent were left with less than 5 percent (see figure 7).21 These income inequality levels are substantially higher than those of China and France and slightly higher than those of Russia and the United States during the same period.

The Culprits: Lebanon’s Political and Business Elites

The causes of Lebanon’s extreme wealth and income inequality are both economic and political. They were exacerbated by the Taif Accord of 1989, which ended the civil war but also reinforced the country’s problematic consociational form of democracy.22 Consociational democracy ensures that each identifiable community is represented in the government and other national institutions and is able to influence policy.23 Theoretically, consociational democracy is advantageous in that it mandates the equitable sharing of power between a multiplicity of groups to prevent civil conflict. However, in practice it can seriously warp governance.24 In the Lebanese case, it provided the elite—the sectarian political leaders—with various means to enrich themselves at the expense of the majority.

The Lebanese brand of consociational democracy created a “party cartel” system. A party cartel is essentially a coalition of elites who are ideologically at loggerheads but who have to share power, often through national unity governments. Lebanon has experienced an overreliance on such governments since the end of the civil war, especially in the years following the assassination of former prime minister Rafik Hariri in 2005 and the Doha Accords of 2008. Due to their fragmented nature and the often conflicting interests of the political parties they represent, national unity governments do not—one might argue, cannot—consistently implement cohesive public policies in the common interest. However, despite their ideological disputes, the elites behind such governments often collude in the matter of plundering the state, protecting their economic privileges, and preventing political competition from upstarts, particularly those who wish to change the system.25

A particularly pernicious aspect of the Lebanese brand of consociational democracy, one that has also served to increase inequality, is that it reinforces and even institutionalizes sectarian identity. In Lebanon, sectarianism figures in every aspect of life: marriage, inheritance, political representation, job applications, land ownership, appointment of judges, and much else. Such institutionalization fosters competition between sects and encourages clientelism. It also hinders the emergence of multi-sectarian political parties that could break this dynamic. In exchange for ordinary people’s support, sectarian leaders provide services such as job placement, reductions in school fees, and healthcare to their communities.26 To maintain these patronage networks, sectarian leaders stoke religiopolitical grievances while blocking the state from assuming responsibility for dispensing the services in question.27 A vicious circle is at play: Consociational democracy paralyzes the state and prevents the adoption of public policies that favor the common good. This, in turn, increases the public’s reliance on sectarian leaders. As a consequence, sectarian leaders continue to enjoy support from the population, retain their economic privileges, and maintain their grip on power.28

The absence of political constraints on sectarian leaders also enabled them to design an economic model favoring their economic privileges, and to do so independently of sectarian and clientelist networks by forging strong alliances with business magnates and bankers. In Lebanon, perhaps more than any other country in the region, business and political elites are connected.29 For instance, as many as eighteen of the country’s twenty top banks have major shareholders linked to political elites, and “individuals closely linked to political elites control 43% of assets in Lebanon’s commercial banking sector.”30 This is significant because, historically, economic sectors dominated by a concentration of politically connected firms prove less competitive.31 The crux of the mutually advantageous relationship between political and business elites is simple: In exchange for major tax breaks, laissez-faire policies, and minimum state intervention, business elites provide regular kickbacks to political elites.32

It is also worth noting that the reconstruction period following the civil war was marked by a neoliberal policy shift close to that observed in Western countries during the 1980s.33 The politico-business elites privatized the economy and facilitated their clique’s massive acquisition of real estate and financial assets, thanks to which they derived massive rent over the following years.34 Political leaders’ appropriation of the country’s resources also explains why Lebanon’s total share of public capital, or government-owned assets used for the public good, is almost certainly very low, although unfortunately it is impossible to derive exact estimates of the Lebanese wealth to income ratio. This is a worrisome sign, as research has shown that the dynamics of public versus private capital is a key mechanism in explaining inequality levels. For example, the rise of income inequality observed worldwide since the 1980s went hand-in-hand with an increase in private capital and a decrease in public capital (see figure 8).35

Two salient examples illustrate how the ruling class slowly destroyed the state at the expense of ordinary Lebanese. The first is the direct looting of the Lebanese treasury, which is the cause of today’s astronomic levels of public debt.36 Since the 1990s, the state has issued public debt in the form of government bonds in Lebanese pounds. These bonds were mostly bought by the Central Bank, domestic Lebanese banks, and other public institutions and had very high interest rates. As a consequence, most of the money the state collected through the bonds was in the end used to repay the interest rather than to fund social welfare programs or public infrastructure. This direct profit scheme enriched bankers as well as anyone who bought the bonds, including the political elites who had issued them in the first place.

The second example is the ruling class’s neglect of the Lebanese public education system. This has had major consequences for social mobility and long-term inequality levels. Indeed, recent research at the World Inequality Lab shows that, for example, Europe is more equal than the United States today, not because it redistributes more income ex post, but because the income distribution pre-taxation is more equal, thanks to stronger public services and free access to education and health. Compared to the rest of the world, the percentage of GDP that is spent on education (public and private) in Lebanon is quite low. Education expenditure represents 2.4 percent of Lebanon’s GDP, compared to 4.8 percent in Turkey, 6 percent in the United States, and 6.3 percent in Norway (see figure 9). Worse yet, it has been decreasing since 2005, when it stood at 3 percent of GDP (see figure 10).

According to the latest available figures, private education institutions in Lebanon attract almost 60 percent of primary school students and 50 percent of secondary school students. Yet private schools are often expensive. In 2013, the average tuition fee for private education in Lebanon was $2,513 per year. The threshold to enter the middle 40 percent of income earners in 2013 was $9,014 PPP (purchasing power parity) per year, with the average standing at $15,165. The average tuition fee of a private school therefore represented 16 percent of the total annual income of the average member of the middle-income group. This partly explains why the already underfunded public sector is overcrowded, with fewer resources per student.

Tax Reform: A Concrete First Step Toward a New Economic Model

The causes of the multiple crises Lebanon currently faces are systemic: The country’s political economy enables the ruling elites to get richer at the expense of the majority and to slowly destroy the state. The solution should therefore be first and foremost political. Given the extent of the problem, however, a massive redesign of the country’s economic model is needed. Among economic reforms, tax policies stand out as particularly well-suited to tackle the extreme levels of poverty and inequality, as well as to raise urgently needed revenues. Fiscal measures alone will not suffice to put Lebanon back on track, and scholars and activists have already suggested a set of complementary reforms.37 However, taxation is key to building a new state and social contract with social justice at their core.

An Inequitable Tax System

Building an efficient and fair tax system should be a cornerstone of any new Lebanese economic model. In this regard, Lebanon enjoys a degree of maneuverability to make significant improvements. The current fiscal system not only does a dismal job of redistributing resources and alleviating poverty, but also of collecting revenue. Tax revenue represented only 15 percent of total GDP in Lebanon in 2017, compared to 21 percent in Chile, a country with a similar income level and that also experienced massive protests last year; 25 percent in the United States; and an average of 34 percent for the countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (see figure 11).38

Moreover, the tax system is structured in such a manner that more prosperous citizens pay less in taxes than their poorer counterparts. First, the system relies mostly on indirect taxation—value-added taxes, excise taxes, tariffs, and other taxes collected through intermediaries such as retail stores. These taxes do not depend on individuals’ levels of income. As such, they hit the poorest segments of society hardest. Taxes collected indirectly represent 65 percent of total tax revenues in Lebanon, as opposed to 25 percent collected through direct taxation. And only 60 percent of the direct taxation is collected through a progressive scheme—that is, with a rate that increases as one’s income increases (see figures 12a and 12b).

In Lebanon, only a part of the Personal Income Tax (PIT) is progressive. Moreover, the PIT—which covers wages as well as profit derived from self-employment, privately owned companies, and certain built property revenues—accounts for only 2 to 3 percent of GDP, which is very low by international standards (see figure 13). The PIT is schedular, which means that instead of taxing an individual’s overall income, it taxes each income stream separately. There are three separate categories of income taxation: business income (profits made by self-employed individuals, partners in partnerships, and individuals in small corporations), which is taxed at rates of 4–21 percent; labor income (salaries, wages, bonuses, allowances, life annuities, pension payments, and other benefits in cash and kind), taxed at rates of 2–20 percent; and built property rental revenues, taxed at rates of 4–14 percent.39

Taxing each source of income separately creates a lack of uniformity in the treatment of taxpayers.Specifically, the system is unfair to those who draw all or most of their income from a single source. This is more often the case among low-income earners, as the rich tend to have diversified sources of income. By taxing each source of income separately, the fiscal administration is likely to underestimate the position of the individual in overall income distribution. Were it to take into account the total amount earned, many taxpayers would find themselves placed in a higher tax bracket.

For example, consider a fictional Lebanese citizen called Ghada, who owns two properties in Beirut—one that she rents out and the other that she personally inhabits. She also works as an employee at a cinema. Ghada appears twice in the fiscal administration files, once for the income she receives from renting out her property and once for her wage. Although her overall income level is quite high, in her capacity as an employee she pays a low income tax on her labor income. Were her overall income taxed—wages plus property revenues, as opposed to each income stream taxed separately—this would bump her up into a higher tax bracket and oblige her to pay more.

Additionally, direct taxes are more rigorously assessed in the case of taxpayers at the bottom than at the top of the income distribution pattern. The result is that labor income earners represented 50 percent of all taxpayers subjected to the PIT in 2005 and 63 percent in 2012. At the same time, tax avoidance in Lebanon is easier for the richest taxpayers. The fiscal law contains many deductions and exemptions, and in certain instances allows individuals to switch from the PIT to a tax category that is exclusively for capital income. Such institutionalized inequality regarding the differential application of methods of control and penalties among taxpayers hinders the intended overall progressivity of the tax system. Additionally, most capital income, which constitutes the biggest share of income for the richest, is taxed at a flat rate. Finally, the Bank Secrecy Law further impedes access to information about well-off taxpayers.40

The Road to Social Justice Passes Through Tax Reform

Lebanon needs to design an income tax that is progressive and also comprehensive, one that taxes all sources of income together and not separately. In this regard, it is important that direct taxation include all types of capital income, certain streams of which—such as interest and capital gains—are not taxed under the current PIT system and are instead subject to a flat and nonprogressive rate. Comprehensive taxation of income is an effective means of raising revenue and of doing so equitably.

Another step Lebanon must take is to significantly increase top marginal tax rates applied to top incomes. Top marginal tax rates in Lebanon are quite low by international standards. The 2019 reform, increasing top rates for labor from 20 to 24 percent and for profits from 21 to 25 percent, was a step in the right direction, but Lebanon still taxes its top income earners much more lightly than France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States, as well as countries from the Global South from 1979 to today (see figures 14a and 14b). In exceptional times, such as wars, top marginal tax rates are commonly hiked. For example, in France, the United Kingdom, Germany, and the United States during the Second World War, they reached 60 and even 80 percent. Lebanon is currently undergoing major political, social, and economic crises that call for such exceptional measures. Doubling the top marginal tax rate to be on par with that of the contemporary United States represents the strict minimum of what should be done.

The next step is wealth taxation. A powerful tool to mitigate extreme income inequality levels, wealth taxation would also finance much-needed welfare services. In this area, two reforms are needed. First, given the exceptional circumstances with the COVID-19 crisis and the Beirut Port explosion buffeting a country already experiencing severe political and financial turmoil, a one-time wealth tax on the richest Lebanese should be assessed for the purpose of funding emergency relief.41

Consider the fact that billionaires in Lebanon (believed to be seven individuals) have a combined net worth of just over 20 percent of the Lebanese national income (see figure 6). Taxing these individuals at a rate of 10 percent would yield a sum equivalent to 2–3 percent of the country’s national income, which is more than what the progressive income tax currently collects from all Lebanese combined.42 And billionaires are only the visible part of the iceberg, as there are many more millionaires. This suggests that even a lower tax rate, when applied to them, would generate significant and much-needed resources.43

The one-off wealth tax should be accompanied by a more comprehensive and progressive wealth tax on property and financial assets, given the importance of the real estate and banking sectors in the Lebanese economy and the amount of income they generate. Regarding property taxation, there is currently a tax on inheritance and a tax on registered built property, which together account for a paltry 0.3 percent of GDP.44 As a first step, the authorities should launch an effort to acquire all relevant data on wealth stock in Lebanon, in particular built property. Armed with such information, the state could proceed to maximize revenue by levying a comprehensive wealth tax that covers financial assets as well as business and nonfinancial assets of all kinds.45

Conclusion: Toward a New State

Without radical political change and serious economic reform, it is easy to imagine Lebanon’s fate. The country’s downward spiral would accelerate. Income and wealth inequality, already endemic and extreme, would worsen. This, in turn, would lead to social unrest, if not outright conflict. The sorry saga ends with Lebanon as a failed state.

Whether the politico-business class that governs Lebanon would agree to urgently required change, and what form such change might take, are open questions. Convincing a long-entrenched and notoriously self-serving clique to cede some of its privileges is a tall order. But today, given the unprecedented severity of the situation in Lebanon, a window of opportunity has presented itself. The popular anger directed at politicians across the spectrum, which skyrocketed following the Beirut Port explosion, might lead the more intuitive among them to conclude that they can no longer ignore calls for reform.

For the others, a cynical message in the language the politicians best understand—that of money and power—seems necessary. The message is simple and blunt: If drastic and immediate economic and political measures are not enacted, nothing of this country’s wealth and resources will remain for them to plunder.

About the Author

Lydia Assouad is an economist at the Paris School of Economics and World Inequality Lab, specializing in political economy, economic history, and development economics with a focus on the Middle East. She is working on the dynamics and roots of economic inequality in the Middle East. She is the author of the articles“Rethinking the Lebanese Economic Miracle: the Extreme Concentration of Income and Wealth in Lebanon,” “Measuring Inequality in the Middle East 1990–2016: The World’s Most Unequal Region?” with Facundo Alvaredo and Thomas Piketty, and “Political Cleavages and Social Inequalities in Algeria, Iraq, and Turkey, 1990–2019” with Amory Gethin, Thomas Piketty, and Juliet-Nil Uraz. She was the El-Erian fellow at the Malcom H. Kerr Carnegie Middle East Center for the year 2019–2020.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The Malcolm H. Kerr Carnegie Middle East Center gratefully acknowledges support from Dr. Mohamed El-Erian that made this publication possible. The views expressed in it are the responsibility of the author alone.

Notes

1Hannes Baumann, “Lebanon’s Economic Crisis Didn’t Happen Overnight. So How Did It Get to This Point?” Monkey Cage (blog), Washington Post, October 22, 2019, https://www.washingtonpost.com/politics/2019/10/22/lebanons-economic-crisis-didnt-happen-overnight-so-how-did-it-get-this-point.

2 Lydia Assouad, “Inequality and Its Discontents in the Middle East,” Carnegie Middle East Center, March 12, 2020, https://carnegie-mec.org/2020/03/12/inequality-and-its-discontents-in-middle-east-pub-81266.

3 “Lebanon Plans to Charge for WhatsApp Calls—Minister,” Reuters, October 17, 2019, https://www.reuters.com/article/lebanon-economy-calls/lebanon-plans-to-charge-for-whatsapp-calls-minister-idUSL5N2724QP.

4 Amer Bisat, “The Tragedy of Doing Nothing,” Carnegie Middle East Center, Diwan, October 21, 2020, https://carnegie-mec.org/diwan/83012.

5 Sunniva Rose, “Le Liban surendetté s’enfonce dans une crise profonde” [Over-Indebted Lebanon Goes Deeper into Crisis], Le Figaro, June 7, 2020, http://www.lefigaro.fr/conjoncture/le-liban-surendette-s-enfonce-dans-une-crise-profonde-20200607​.

6 “Half of Lebanese Businesses Could Close in 2020: Chammas,” Daily Star, June 16, 2020, https://www.dailystar.com.lb/Business/Local/2020/Jun-16/507563-half-of-lebanese-businesses-could-close-in-2020-chammas.ashx.

7 Dana Khreiche, “Lebanon Inflation Soars Past 100% in Latest Sign of Meltdown,” Bloomberg, August 26, 2020, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2020-08-26/lebanon-inflation-soars-past-100-in-fallout-from-currency-shock​. See also Chloe Cornish (@ChloeNCornish), “Lebanon’s economic melt-down gets worse,” Twitter post, August 26, 2020, https://twitter.com/ChloeNCornish/status/1298592128407347205.

8 Lynn Sheikh Moussa, “Lebanese at Risk of Famine as Poverty Soars,” Beirut Today, July 1, 2020, https://beirut-today.com/2020/07/01/lebanese-risk-famine-poverty-soars.

9 Sunniva Rose, “Lebanon: Suicide of Indebted Father Sparks Anger as Economic Woes Grow,” The National, December 3, 2019, http://www.thenational.ae/world/mena/lebanon-suicide-of-indebted-father-sparks-anger-as-economic-woes-grow-1.946098.

10 Inequality in the Lebanese political economy has long manifested itself in the state’s treatment of refugees and migrant workers. The latter are discriminated against in countless ways, especially through the kafala sponsorship system—which critics describe as a modern form of slavery. See Amnesty International, “Lebanon: Abandoned Migrant Domestic Workers Must Be Protected,” June 3, 2020, http://www.amnesty.org/en/latest/news/2020/06/lebanon-abandoned-migrant-domestic-workers-must-be-protected. See also Amnesty International, “Their House Is My Prison: Exploitation of Migrant Domestic Workers in Lebanon,” 2019, https://www.amnesty.org/download/Documents/MDE1800222019ENGLISH.pdf.

11 Timour Azhari, “Lebanon Faces Painful Reforms to Unlock Foreign Aid,” Al Jazeera, May 12, 2020, https://www.aljazeera.com/ajimpact/lebanon-faces-painful-reforms-unlock-foreign-aid-200512190902820.html.

12 For an in-depth analysis of the evolution of the economic situation, the recent collapse, and the issue of international aid, see Charbel Nahas, Une économie et un Etat pour le Liban [also available in English as An Economy and a State for Lebanon], (Beirut: Riad El-Rayyes Books, 2020).

13 Lebanon has long stood out among Arab countries by virtue of having the oldest liberal market system in the region and having constantly opted for a laissez-faire economic system with a free market, openness to trade, and minimum state intervention. See Rana Jawad, Social Welfare and Religion in the Middle East: A Lebanese Perspective (Bristol: Policy Press, 2009), 21; and Toufic Gaspard, A Political Economy of Lebanon, 1948–2002: The Limits of Laissez-Faire (Leiden: Brill, 2004), 54.

14 The study was commissioned by Lebanon’s ministry of planning and implemented by the French International Institute for Research and Training for Standardized Development (IRFED). See Stéphane Malsagne, “Le père Lebret, chroniquer de l’Etat libanais en construction” [Father Lebret, chronicler of the Lebanese state during construction], Jadaliyya, November 26, 2014, http://www.jadaliyya.com/Details/31513.

15 In the middle were 14 and 32 percent population groups earning 28 and 22 percent of the national income, respectively.

16 Lydia Assouad, “Rethinking the Lebanese Economic Miracle: The Extreme Concentration of Income and Wealth in Lebanon 2005–2014,” WID.world working paper series number 2017/13, World Inequality Lab, September 19, 2018, https://wid.world/document/rethinking-lebanese-economic-miracle-extreme-concentration-income-wealth-lebanon-2005-2014-wid-world-working-paper-201713, also available at https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-02160275.

17 Emmanuel Saez, “Top Incomes in the United States and Canada Over the Twentieth Century,” Journal of the European Economic Association 3, no. 2/3 (2005): 402-11, www.jstor.org/stable/40004983. See also Wojciech Kopczuk, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song, “Earnings Inequality and Mobility in the United States: Evidence from Social Security Data Since 1937,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, no. 1 (February 2010), 91–128, https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2010.125.1.91.

18 The fiscal data provided by the Ministry of Finance are individual micro data. Three sources of income are reported separately: business income, salaries and wages, and housing rental income (excluding revenues of people living in their own dwelling). For business income and wages, what is reported consists of gross income (before any deduction and gross expenses), taxable income (after deductions of charges and benefits), and the amount of tax paid. For rental revenues, only the last two variables are reported.

19This is particularly true of Syrian residents of Lebanon. See Roberta Gatti, Diego F. Angel-Urdinola, Joana Silva, and András Bodor, Striving for Better Jobs: The Challenge of Informality in the Middle East and North Africa, World Bank, MENA Knowledge and Learning Quick Notes Series no. 49, 86, http://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/445141468275941540/pdf/Striving-for-better-jobs-the-challenge-of-informality-in-the-Middle-East-and-North-Africa.pdf.

20 International Monetary Fund, Middle East and Central Asia Department, Lebanon: 2016 Article IV Consultation-Press Release; Staff Report; and Statement by the Executive Director for Lebanon, January 24, 2017, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/CR/Issues/2017/01/24/Lebanon-2016-Article-IV-Consultation-Press-Release-Staff-Report-and-Statement-by-the-44572.

21 See Lydia Assouad, “Rethinking the Lebanese Economic Miracle: The Extreme Concentration of Income and Wealth in Lebanon.” Note that the author computed a hypothetical average wealth distribution using wealth statistics available in the World Inequality Database and adjusted the top of the distribution to account for Lebanese billionaires’ weight, using Pareto interpolation techniques. All data sources and codes to derive the wealth inequality figures are available online on the World Inequality Database website: https://wid.world/news-article/new-paper-inequality-lebanon.

22 See Fawwaz Trabulsi, Social Classes and Political Power in Lebanon (unpublished manuscript “produced with the financial assistance of the Heinrich Böll Stiftung—Middle East Office”), https://lb.boell.org/sites/default/files/fawaz_english_draft.pdf.

23 Arend Lijphart, “Consociational Democracy,” World Politics 21, no. 2 (January 1969), 207–225, https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/world-politics/article/consociational-democracy/BB47BF2A5A4EBAE341FD3FA4E262410F.

24 Ian S. Spears, “Africa: The Limits of Power-Sharing,” Journal of Democracy 13, no. 3 (2002), 123-136, https://muse.jhu.edu/article/17227/pdf.

25 Christiana Parreira, “Another Unity Government Won’t Solve Lebanon’s Crisis,” Monkey Cage (blog), Washington Post, August 20, 2020, https://www.washingtonpost.com/politics/2020/08/20/another-unity-government-wont-solve-lebanons-crisis/?utm_source=twitter&utm_medium=social&utm_campaign=wp_monkeycage.

26 Melani Cammett, “Lebanon, the Sectarian Identity Test Lab,” The Century Foundation, April 10, 2019, http://www.tcf.org/content/report/lebanon-sectarian-identity-test-lab/?agreed=1.

27 See the extensive work by Bassel Salloukh, including The Politics of Sectarianism in Postwar Lebanon (co-authored with Rabie Barakat, Jinan S. Al-Habbal, Lara W. Khattab, and Shoghig Mikaelian) (London: Pluto Press, 2015).

28 For more, see Melani Cammett, Compassionate Communalism: Welfare and Sectarianism in Lebanon (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2014).

29 Ishac Diwan, Adeel Malik, and Izak Atiyas, Crony Capitalism in the Middle East – Business and Politics from Liberalization to the Arab Spring (Oxford University Press, 2019).

30 Jad Chaaban, “I’ve Got the Power: Mapping Connections between Lebanon’s Banking Sector and the Ruling Class,” Economic Research Forum Working Paper Series, no. 1059, October 2016, http://www.erf.org.eg/publications/ive-got-the-power-mapping-connections-between-lebanons-banking-sector-and-the-ruling-class.

31 While such a situation is mirrored in Lebanon, an interesting feature of Lebanese crony capitalism is that the phenomenon is not backed by a strong state, as is the case in Egypt, Morocco, Syria, and Tunisia. See Ishac Diwan and Jamal Ibrahim Haidar, “Political Connections Reduce Job Creation: Firm-level Evidence From Lebanon,” Journal of Development Studies, forthcoming, https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/haidar/files/diwanhaidar-pcjc-01142017.pdf.

32 Hannes Baumann, Citizen Hariri: Lebanon’s Neo-Liberal Reconstruction (Oxford University Press, 2017).

33 See Georges Corm, Le Liban contemporain: Histoire et société [Contemporary Lebanon: History and Society], (Paris: Éditions La Découverte, 2012) and Hannes Baumann, Citizen Hariri: Lebanon’s Neo-Liberal Reconstruction. Both also offer analysis of the distributional effect of the reconstruction policies and the macroeconomic climate between 1990 and 2005.

34 Sami Halabi and Jacob Boswall, “Extend and Pretend: Lebanon’s Financial House of Cards,” Triangle, Who Will Foot the Bill? Working Series, November 2019, http://www.thinktriangle.net/wp-content/uploads/2019/11/Extend_Pretend_Lebanons_Financial_House_of_Cards_2019.pdf. See also Rosalie Berthier, “Grand Theft Lebanon,” Synaps, April 14, 2020, https://synaps.network/post/lebanon-finance-economy-ponzi-bankrupt.

35 World Inequality Lab, Word Inequality Report 2018: Executive Summary, 14(Figure E6), https://wir2018.wid.world.

36 For more, see Nisreen Salti, “No Country for Poor Men: How Lebanon’s Debt Has Exacerbated Inequality,” Carnegie Middle East Center, https://carnegie-mec.org/2019/09/17/no-country-for-poor-men-how-lebanon-s-debt-has-exacerbated-inequality-pub-79852.

37 Sami Atallah et al., “For An Emergency Economic Rescue Plan For Lebanon,” Carnegie Middle East Center, November 10, 2019, https://carnegie-mec.org/2019/11/10/for-emergency-economic-rescue-plan-for-lebanon-pub-80307.

38 OECD (2020), “Tax Revenue (Indicator),” OECD Data, accessed December 15, 2020, https://data.oecd.org/tax/tax-revenue.htm.

39 Other capital income (dividends incomes, board member appropriations from profits, and interest incomes, including interest on bonds and treasury bills) is taxed separately at a flat rate of 10 percent. See Karim Daher, Les Impôts au Liban [Taxation in Lebanon], (Beirut: Librairie Antoine, 2002).

40 Ibid. The corporate tax rate is 17 percent. Interest incomes, dividends, and capital gains are taxed at 7 percent, 10 percent, and 15 percent, respectively.

41 On this point, see ESCWA, “Wealth Inequality and Closing the Poverty Gap in Arab Countries: The Case for a Solidarity Wealth Tax,” 2020, https://www.unescwa.org/publications/wealth-inequality-closing-poverty-gap-arab-countries.

42 At least $1.5 billion, according to the 2018 GDP figures.

43 See also Nabil Abdo and Shaddin Almasri, “For a Decade of Hope Not Austerity in the Middle East and North Africa,” OXFAM International, August 27, 2020, https://www.oxfam.org/en/research/decade-hope-not-austerity-middle-east-and-north-africa.

44 See Brunot Marot and Alexa Moukarzel-Héchaimé, “La fiscalité foncière au Liban” [Property Taxes in Lebanon], La revue fiscale Libanaise, 2015, 12–31, https://www.academia.edu/30992005/La_fiscalit%C3%A9_fonci%C3%A8re_au_Liban.

45 On the feasibility of the introduction of wealth taxes, see Juliana Londoño-Velez and Javier Ávila-Mahecha, “Can Wealth Taxation Work in Developing Countries? Quasi-Experimental Evidence from Colombia,” Job Market Paper, November 29, 2018, https://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/course/londono-wealth2018.pdf.

Carnegie does not take institutional positions on public policy issues; the views represented herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of Carnegie, its staff, or its trustees.